Hostname: page-component-586b7cd67f-vdxz6 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-29T22:01:00.727Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

The Old South's Stake in the Inter-Regional Movement of Slaves, 1850–1860

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  11 May 2010

Laurence J. Kotlikoff
Affiliation:
Harvard University
Sebastian Pinera
Affiliation:
Harvard University

Abstract

The Old South's economic stake in western land expansion and slave migration is examined in a two-region, general equilibrium model of slave mobility. The model separates the effect on the Old South's assets and slave population of more western land from that of slave sales per se. The authors conclude that the Old South had no economic stake in the New South. The most conservative estimate reveals that a doubling of western lands in 1850 would have increased Old South wealth by less than two percent.

Type
Articles
Copyright
Copyright © The Economic History Association 1977

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

1 Conrad, Alfred H. and Meyer, John R., “The Economics of Slavery in the Antebellum South,” in The Reinterpretation of American Economic History, ed. Fogel, Robert W. and Engerman, Stanley L. (New York: Harper & Row, 1971), pp. 95130Google Scholar; and Sutch, Richard, “The Breeding of Slaves for Sale and the Westward Expansion of Slavery, 1850–1860,”Southern Economic History Project Working Paper No. 10, Institute of Business and Economic Research, University of California, Berkeley,November 1972Google Scholar. Eastern states and Old South are used here synonymously.

2 Passel, Peter and Wright, Gavin, “The Effects of Pre-Civil War Territorial Expansion on the Price of Slaves,” Journal of Political Economy, vol. 80, no. 6 (1972), pp. 1188–202CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

3 We are interested here in the expansion's effect on eastern wealth through its impact on product prices and slave movements. We leave as an open question whether large numbers of eastern planters earned significantly higher returns on their own entrepreneurial talents by themselves moving westward. For the purposes of our analysis, then, we shall permit only slaves to move from East to West keeping the other factors of production, land, capital, and white managerial labor, fixed in the East. These three non-slave inputs form a composite input referred to as “land “below. The probable error involved in assuming only slaves moved West seems small. As Fogel and Engerman assert, “On a majority of the large plantations the top nonownership management was black.” See Fogel, Robert W. and Engerman, Stanley L., Time on the Cross, vol. I (Boston, 1974), 212Google Scholar.

4 Indeed the Mississippi Constitution expressly prohibited the importation of slaves for sale from 1833 and 1837. Despite this constitutional prohibition, the Mississippi legislature placed a 2.5 percent tax on the trade during the period, rather than enforce the prohibition. See Syndor, Charles S., Slavery in Mississippi, (American Historical Association, Mass., 1965), pp. 162–68Google Scholar.

5 Note that the output supply functions take factor marginal products as parameters, while the slave excess demand and supply curves are developed with output price as a parameter.

6 Strictly speaking this is only correct for a rising price of output; if the price of output falls no exportation will take place. On the other hand, since MPsw > MPsw, slaves would not be shipped back to the East. The supply curves Yes and Yws become perfectly inelastic for a price decline.

7 “Agriculture Census of the United States 1860,” Joseph C. G. Kennedy, Superintendent (Washington: Government Printing Office, 1864), pp. 185–87. This Census gives production by state of tobacco and cotton. Cotton prices were taken from Gray, Lewis Cecil, History of Agriculture in the Southern United States to 1860, vol. II (New York, 1941), 765Google Scholar.

8 The most appropriate mechanism to analyze this issue is a model permitting two distinct outputs with distinct demands in the East, and one output, cotton in the West. Unfortunately lack of empirical information such as the number of exports of slaves from tobacco vs. cotton states precludes this option. Hence we are forced to deal with a composite tobacco-cotton output in the East.

9 Sutch, “Breeding of Slaves,” pp. 42–58.

10 Robert W. Fogel and Stanley L. Engerman, “The Market Evaluation of Human Capital: The Case of Slavery,” unpublished paper presented to the Annual Cliometrics Conference at Madison, Wisconsin, April 27–29, 1972, Charts III and IV.

11 Prior to 1850 slaves were measured in nondecimal age units; in addition the age categories chosen are different for each census. While it remains possible to obtain an aggregate volume of exports, an export age breakdown for those pre-1850 decades is not forthcoming. Nor is it possible to obtain age group survival rates for the entire slave population due to varying classification procedure

12 See Sutch, “Breeding of Slaves,” p. 10, and Fogel and Engerman, Time on the Cross, p. 47.

13 Fogel and Engerman, Time on the Cross, p. 44.